• Ingen resultater fundet

Empirical strategy

In document Essays on International Trade (Sider 65-68)

Chapter 2 - Technology and Global Value Chains:

3. Empirical strategy

est is the firm’s offshoring to low- and middle income countries. This specification hence means that our regressions make use of the variation in robot exposure and offshoring over time, within a firm.

3.1 Measuring exposure to industrial robots

We derive the firm-year specific measure for robot exposure using data from the Interna-tional Federation of Robotics (IFR). The IFR provides global sales and operaInterna-tional stock of industrial robots by ’application’, where applications are activities like ’metal casting’

or ’plastic moulding’ or ’arc welding’. This lends itself well to mapping these applications to the occupations conducting similar tasks and measuring the extent to which different occupations are exposed to these robot types. In a similar vain to Graetz and Michaels (2018) we hand match these robot applications to ISCO occupation codes. In contrast to Graetz and Michaels(2018), however, we use the dates of when sales of robot applications switched to be non-zero to include a time dimension.

Our procedure is the following: in each time period we define a 4 digit occupation code as ’automatable’ using industrial robots if its title or formal description contains any of the words included in the application titles of the IFR data and if the IFR global opera-tional stock of robots for that application is non-zero in that year. Examples of matched occupations are ’Metal casters’, which maps to ’Metal casting’ as an application in the IFR data or the occupation ’Machine tool operators’ matching to the ’Handling operations at machine tools’ IFR application.3

After we have identified occupation-years that relate to the capabilities of industrial robots, we calculate theautomatablesharefor each firm. That is the share of workers that could potentially be replaced by an industrial robot by a given year. For firmiin base year tbasethe automation share is then:

automatable shareitbase = Pn

o=1automatableot×emploitbase Pn

o=1emploitbase (9)

whereautomatableotis a dummy variable with value 1 if occupation codeois replaceable by

3TableA2in the appendix provides the full list of ISCO 68 occupations that could be automated according

industrial robots in yeartandemploitbaseis the number of employees of occupationoin firm iintbase. Allowing theautomatableotdummy to be time dependent enables us to account for the availability of new industrial robots that only became commercially available at some point in our sample period. In the next step we make use of industry-year specific global stock of industrial robots global robot stockjt provided by the IFR. For firmiin industryj the final measure of time varying ’robot exposure’ becomes,

robot exposureijt =automatable shareitbase×global robot stockjt (10) TableA1illustrates the mean automation share of firms in the base year and the stock of industrial robots reported by the International Federation of Robotics. Our handmatch-ing procedure between occupation codes and robot tasks appears to performs well, since the industries with the highest automation potential are also the industries with the high-est stock of industrial robots. Given we are using a fixed effects specification, within a firm, the variation in robot exposure across years is driven by industry-year specific sales of industrial robots. The variation in robot exposure across firms is coming from several sources: the share of automatable employment in the base year, the availability of new types of robots over time and industry specific sales.

3.2 Measuring offshoring and shocks to the global trading environment

The literature has suggested several ways to measure the relocation of production activ-ities to foreign countries using import data. We are interested in the value of imported inputs that can substitute for employment in the firm in Denmark and hence want to ex-clude imports of raw materials used in the production process. Therefore we apply the definition of narrow offshoring as outlined inHummels et al.(2014) by calculating the to-tal value of imported HS4 products that the firm also sells domestically and/ or exports.

In the following, we outline how we control for changes in the global trading environ-ment that affect Danish firms. The most important high income offshoring partner coun-try of Danish manufacturing firms in our sample is Germany. The machinery induscoun-try is

particularly interlinked with Germany. If we take, for example, the HS6 product 848340 – ”gears and gearing” that is offshored to Germany, an idiosyncratic shock to the supply of gears of German manufacturers exporting to the world market will affect the subset of Danish firms that offshored gears to Germany. This change in the trading environment is exogenous for the Danish offshorer and product-by-partner country specific. To separate the effect of automation on offshoring from the effect of trade shocks on offshoring we include a control for the trading environment in baseline specification8.

To control for firm-year specific trade shocks we use the instrument introduced to the literature byHummels et al.(2014). At first we calculate the World Exports Supply (WES).

The WES,Icptis countryc’s export of HS6 productpto the world market at timetminus its supply to Denmark. Then we calculate the sharessicpof each country x product combina-tioncpon total offshoring in the pre-sample year of firmi. The final measure for changes in the trading environment,Citfor firmiin yeartis the sum over country x product specific WES,Icptweighted by the firm‘s country x product specific pre-sample sharessicp.

Cit=X

cp

sicpIcpt (11)

Since we are interested in offshoring overall, and offshoring to high income and low and middle income countries separately, we calculate three different control variables for shocks in the trading environment for each of these groups.

In document Essays on International Trade (Sider 65-68)