• Ingen resultater fundet

Kopi fra DBC Webarkiv

N/A
N/A
Info
Hent
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Del "Kopi fra DBC Webarkiv"

Copied!
25
0
0

Indlæser.... (se fuldtekst nu)

Hele teksten

(1)

Kopi fra DBC Webarkiv

Kopi af:

Working paper : WP : Economic satisfaction and income rank in small neighbourhoods

Dette materiale er lagret i henhold til aftale mellem DBC og udgiveren.

www.dbc.dk

e-mail: dbc@dbc.dk

(2)

WORKING PAPER 08-25

Andrew E. Clark, Nicolai Kristensenand Niels Westergård-Nielsen

Economic Satisfaction and Income Rank in Small Neighbourhoods

Department of Economics

(3)

Economic Satisfaction and Income Rank in Small Neighbourhoods

Andrew E. Clark*, Nicolai Kristensen**and Niels Westergård-Nielsen***

Abstract

We contribute to the literature on well-being and comparisons by appealing to new Danish data dividing the country up into around 9,000 small neighbourhoods.

Administrative data provides us with the income of every person in each of these neighbourhoods. This income information is matched to demographic and economic satisfaction variables from eight years of Danish ECHP data. Panel regression analysis shows that, conditional on own household income, respondents report higher satisfaction levels when their neighbours are richer. However, individuals are rank-sensitive: conditional on own income and neighbourhood median income, respondents are more satisfied as their percentile neighbourhood ranking improves. A ten percentage point rise in rank (i.e. from 40th to 20th position in a 200-household cell) is worth 0.11 on a one to six scale, which is a large marginal effect in satisfaction terms.

Keywords: Satisfaction, Neighbours, Income Comparisons, Geo-coded Data.

JEL codes: C23, C25, D84, J28, J31, J33.

* Corresponding Author. Andrew.Clark@ens.fr. Paris School of Economics, IZA, and CCP, Aarhus School of Business, University of Aarhus; ** Danish Institute of Governmental Research and CCP, Aarhus School of Business, University of Aarhus; ***

CCP, Aarhus School of Business, University of Aarhus, and IZA. We thank the Rockwool Research Unit, Anna Piil Damm and Marie Louise Schultz-Nielsen for letting us use their work on the geo-coded data, and Anna Piil Damm, Andrew Oswald, Dan Wilson and seminar participants at the EEA conference (Milan) and an anonymous referee for very useful comments.

(4)

1 Getting to Know Your Neighbours

The empirical estimation of social interactions in Economics, which includes the recent work on relative utility, has one essential requirement:

identifying those with whom you interact, or who are in the reference group. The broad idea is that individuals compare to, or interact with, others who are in some sense close to them. These can be individuals with whom they identify (salience) or those that they see very often.1

While many different kinds of salient reference groups can be justified ex ante, it is nigh on impossible to actually prove that any retained reference group defined by observable individual characteristics (such as age, sex and education) is the “right” one. A frequency of interaction criterion, which will include family, friends, work colleagues, and neighbours, is perhaps easier to defend. It is to this second type of physical closeness, and in particular to neighbours, that we appeal in this paper, to tease out the relationship between individual well-being and others’ income.

A number of existing papers have carried out just such an exercise.

Luttmer (2005) showed that individual life satisfaction was positively correlated with own income, but negatively correlated with average income by local area in a number of waves of the US National Survey of Families and Households. Similar findings on American, Canadian, Latin American, and South African data are reported by Blanchflower and Oswald (2004), Graham and Felton (2006), Helliwell and Huang (2005) and Kingdon and Knight (2007), respectively.

Even so, while the motivation for comparing to those who are physically close may seem unimpeachable, there does remain the difficulty of measurement.

How can we calculate average income (or some other moment) at a finely- disaggregated level? Survey data is at a disadvantage here. While surveys do provide information on individual well-being, there are rarely enough respondents to provide anything like accurate information at the very local level, producing substantial measurement error, or even empty cells.

Most external datasets also suffer from the same drawbacks as the original survey, leading to relatively aggregated “local” areas that may be thought to stretch the definition of neighbours a little too far. The solution we take here is to match in external data, using population-based information on local neighbourhood

1 Alternatively, the reference group can be directly controlled in an experiment, as in Clark et al. (2008b) and McBride (2007).

(5)

characteristics. Particular attention is paid to the homogeneity of the households within these small neighbourhoods, as described below.

2 Matched Geo-coded Data

This paper is based on data of unusual richness. Eight waves of survey data from the Danish sample of the European Community Household Panel (ECHP)2 have been merged with administrative records. The ECHP survey data, which constitute a panel spanning 1994-2001, cover about 7,000 individuals in the first few years. Due to sample attrition this falls to about 5,000 individuals by 2001.

The dependent variable is satisfaction with economic conditions, which is our proxy measure of utility. This is formulated as follows: “How satisfied are you with your economic conditions? (Please indicate your satisfaction on a scale from 1-6 where 1 signifies “not satisfied at all” and 6 signifies “fully satisfied)”. The distribution of responses to this question is shown in Figure 1. We assume that the respondent’s answer to this question applies to how well the whole household is doing, not just the individual him/herself. The empirical analysis will therefore relate the respondent’s answer to household income: both her own and those in the neighbourhood.

The Danish component of the ECHP was sampled randomly from the central administrative database, the Central Personal Register (CPR). The CPR contains an entry for each individual in Denmark; each individual has a unique CPR number.

The geo-referenced data comes from a newly-developed data set described in Damm and Schultz-Nielsen (2008). This data set is based on a geographical grid of size 100 by 100 meters (i.e. 10,000 square meters, or a hectare) covering the entire country. Some of these hectare cells are not inhabited, while others are only very thinly inhabited which poses data confidentiality problems – around two- thirds of inhabited hectare cells contain under five households. Damm and Schultz- Nielsen (2008) have therefore used an aggregation technique to produce clusters of neighbouring hectare cells, where each cluster includes a minimum of 150 households. A second clustering exercise uses the same strategy to produce clusters containing at least 600 households. The priorities in the clustering process were to obtain a classification that does not change over time, is marked out by physical barriers and is compact, consists of contiguous hectare cells, and is relatively homogenous in terms of type and ownership of housing. In particular, they make sure that the resulting clusters do not contain a major road or waterway, or a

2 See http://epp.eurostat.cec.eu.int for details of the ECHP data.

(6)

similar natural boundary. As such, no cluster contains households that are “both sides of the tracks”. Their adjustment process also ensures that an area which consists of mainly single homes is not in the same cluster as an area with blocks of flats (see Damm and Schultz-Nielsen, 2008, for more details).

This clustering process transforms the original 431,233 inhabited hectare cells into 9,404 and 2,296 small and large neighbourhoods respectively (defined by containing a minimum of 150 and 600 households respectively). Figure 2 shows some of the resulting small neighbourhoods in the area of Taastrupgård, Høje Tåstrup (a suburb of Copenhagen). The dots refer to individual addresses which were defined by the government to be “socially-exposed” (in the Government’s Programme Committee for Avoidance of Ghetto areas). The neighbourhoods here match the area well (although the fit is less good in other areas). In general Figure 2 brings out that the constructed neighbourhoods are small: Taastrupgård is divided into three small neighbourhoods of 313, 274 and 289 households in 2004, each containing between 5 and 7 hectare cells (the addresses indicated by the dots in Figure 2 are thus obviously multi-household dwellings).

We then merge the ECHP data to these small neighbourhoods, matching via the ECHP respondent’s CPR number. Not all small neighbourhoods contain an ECHP respondent, and our regression analysis covers just over 4,000 of the 9,404 small neighbourhoods mentioned above.

The resulting merged file contains individual-level information, such as demographics (although we will not use the ECHP income information, as discussed below) and our dependent variable, satisfaction with economic conditions. It also contains aggregated information regarding the neighbourhood in which the ECHP respondent lives. This aggregate information on neighbours can take many forms, covering income, earnings, education, and occupation, for example, but also detailed housing characteristics and even behaviours such as new car purchases (again in great detail). The individual-level information refers to all years of the ECHP (1994-2001), while neighbourhood information is available for all years from 1980-2004.

We wish to use this mix of individual- and local-level information to consider the broad question of social interactions. There are a number of ways of looking for evidence of these, as listed below.

• Modelling the behaviour of individual i (ai) as a function of that of her peer group (ai*), where a might represent car ownership, for example:

ai = f(ai*, ….).

• Modelling the utility of individual i (Ui) as a function of both her own and her peer group’s behaviour: Ui = u(ai, ai*, ….).

(7)

• Modelling the utility of individual i (Vi) as a function of both her own and her peer group’s income: Vi = v(yi, yi*, ….).

We here consider the last of these, and wish to show that individual well- being is affected by not only own but also peer-group income. Empirical estimation of these kinds of social interactions has been bedeviled by three measurement issues: those of utility, income, and the peer group itself.

For the first of these we appeal to a satisfaction variable, the validity of which has been addressed in Clark et al. (2008a), for example. Second, our key right-hand side variable is income. This is obtained from administrative data for both the ECHP respondent and the local neighbourhood (we therefore do not use ECHP self-reported income), and is arguably fairly free from measurement error because it is double-checked by individuals and employers. We consider household equivalent income (converted using the OECD scale), expressed in real terms in 1980 Danish Kroner. Last, the peer group here consists of the neighbours in the small neighbourhoods, as described above.

The following section shows how own and others’ income are related to economic satisfaction in eight years of panel data.

3 Economic Satisfaction and Neighbourhood Income

We exploit the panel nature of our data to run fixed-effect regressions.

Table 1 shows some of the results from fixed-effect linear estimation (“within”

regressions) of economic satisfaction. The sample consists of around 34,000 observations on 6,800 individuals in 4,000 small neighbourhoods. The two income variables are log of own household annual income, and log of the median household annual income in the neighbourhood (which is less sensitive to outliers than the mean). These both attract positive and significant coefficients in the first column of Table 1. Not only do individuals feel better off as their own income grows, they also feel better off as they live with richer neighbours. Note that these are fixed-effect panel regressions, so they are not driven by the inherently satisfied seeking out richer areas. Re-estimating column 1 as a pooled cross-section with clustered standard errors produces a very similar estimated coefficient on neighbourhood income (but a larger estimated coefficient on own household income: “happy” people do indeed earn more).

The regressions in Table 1 also control for a variety of other variables, such as age (which continues to be U-shaped, even within individuals), education, number of years in the neighbourhood, and so on. These mostly attract estimated

(8)

coefficients which are consistent with those in the literature. We also control for degree of interaction with neighbours (a dummy variable for talking to them at least twice a week), which attracts a negative but insignificant estimated coefficient.

The results in column 1 may at first sight seem inconsistent with a literature that has insisted on income comparisons in individual well-being. The particular nature of the peer group here may explain why. Having richer neighbours may make me feel worse off in a relative income sense, but have positive spillovers in creating local community social capital. This latter might work through criminality and anti-social behaviour, or via the creation (and funding) of local projects. While it is hard to test directly for many of these, we can address the issue of whether I like having richer neighbours because they pay more taxes and thus provide me with better amenities. Local taxes are not collected at the small neighbourhood level, but rather at the municipality level. To see whether local taxes might explain my preference for rich neighbours, we add, in column 2 of Table 1, a variable showing median municipality household income to the regression. This attracts a completely insignificant coefficient, while that on neighbourhood income remains positive and significant.

We have previously hinted that richer neighbours may induce two counteracting effects: a feeling of lower relative income, but also the possibility of creating local public goods. The final column of Table 1 is a first pass at empirically distinguishing between these two concepts. Here we introduce three income variables: own and neighbourhood income, as in column 1, but also the individual household’s normalized rank in the local income distribution (defined as: rank in neighbourhood / number of households in neighbourhood). Normalised rank is just over zero for the poorest household in the neighbourhood, and one for the richest household. Income rank has previously been appealed to in the context of job satisfaction (Brown et al., 2008) and effort at work (Clark et al., 2008b).

The advantage of normalized rank in this context is that it is unit-free, which helps us to control for the local public goods interpretation. Own household income and median neighbourhood household income together only inform us whether the respondent lives in a household which is in the top or bottom half of the local income distribution. For those above the median, a tighter distribution of local income produces higher rank, whereas for those beneath the median, higher rank comes from a wider distribution.

Rank therefore includes information about the second moment of the income distribution that is perhaps less germane for public-good provision, but is

(9)

central in determining my own position in the local income ranking. We therefore include it explicitly as a third explanatory variable of economic satisfaction.

The results in column 3 show that, conditional on own and neighbourhood median income, local income rank is strongly positively correlated with economic satisfaction. A rise of ten percentage points in rank is associated with economic satisfaction which is 0.11 higher on the one to six scale: this is a substantial effect.

The addition of rank drives the coefficient on own household income down, and that on neighbourhood median income up. This is to be expected. The results in the first column of Table 1 arguably combined several different phenomena. A part of the positive return to own household income is that local rank rises; equally greater median neighbourhood income reduces my own rank, ceteris paribus. Once we control for these rank effects, it is to be expected that own income matters less, and others’ income matters more. The estimated coefficients on all three income variables are significant at the 5% level.

The results in Table 1 suggest the presence of both a local public goods and a relative income effect. There is much more analysis that we could carry out in order to both test the robustness of these findings, and to aid with their interpretation. A number of these concern the exact form of the income terms in the regression. While we have entered income in logs (as is normal in this literature) it would be worthwhile looking at some more general polynomial specification. We could also explicitly consider a separate effect of having income under the neighbourhood mean or median (i.e. a kind of loss aversion). Last, while we have entered normalized rank as a simple number between 0 and 1, there is a case to be made for rank being much more important towards the top of the distribution than around the middle, so that the rank effect might be convex.

The second set of tests concern the interpretation of the coefficients on our income variable. An alternative reading of the neighbours’ income result is that I don’t necessarily want to have rich neighbours per se, but I do like to have neighbours who have the kind of characteristics that attract higher incomes: for example, prime-age, married, and well-educated. The natural test here would then be to introduce increasing numbers of neighbourhood demographic variables to see if these are behind the positive neighbourhood income coefficient in Table 1. Last, we can try to find explicit measures of local public goods, and evaluate whether this channel explains individuals’ liking for richer neighbours. We hope to address all of these issues in future work.

(10)

4 Conclusion

A common theme in the subjective well-being literature has been comparisons to others, but no agreement has been reached on who are these others.

One natural definition is in terms of geographical or social distance; the people with whom you rub shoulders every day (friends, colleagues, family, and neighbours). The drawback is that many surveys do not contain sufficient information on these individuals to be useful. Matching from external data sources requires us to identify the respondent’s firm or local neighbourhood. While some work has appealed to such matching, the “neighbourhoods” in question often turn out to be very large indeed.

Danish register data allows us to overcome this drawback, by appealing to many thousands of small neighbourhoods (containing a minimum of 150 households) and administrative data regarding the incomes of everyone in Denmark. We can thus construct truly “local” measures of income, amongst many other things.

We match individual economic satisfaction scores from eight years of ECHP data to measures of both own income and neighbourhood median income, both derived from administrative data. Our first main finding from panel regressions is that individuals report higher satisfaction levels when their neighbours are richer. Our second finding is that individuals are nonetheless sensitive to their relative position with respect to their neighbours: moving from the 51st percentile to the 100th percentile of the small neighbourhood income distribution is predicted to raise satisfaction by 0.55 points on a one to six scale.

While richer neighbours appear to be welcome, being at the top of the pile still counts.

(11)

References

Blanchflower, David G. and Oswald, Andrew J. (2004). “Well-being over time in Britain and the USA.” Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1359-1386.

Bolster, Ann, Burgess, Simon, Johnston, Ron, Jones, Kelvyn, Propper, Carol and Saker, Rebecca (2004). “Neighbourhoods, Households and Income Dynamics:

A Semi-Parametric Investigation of Neighbourhood Effects.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4611.

Brown, Gordon D.A., Gardner, Jonathan, Oswald, Andrew J. and Qian, Jing (2008). “Does Wage Rank Affect Employees' Wellbeing?” Industrial Relations, 47, 355-389.

Clark, Andrew E., Frijters, Paul and Shields, Michael (2008a). “Relative Income, Happiness and Utility: An Explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and Other Puzzles.” Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 95-144.

Clark, Andrew E., Masclet, David and Villeval, Marie-Claire (2008b). “Effort and Comparison Income.” CEP Discussion Paper No. 0886.

Damm, Anne P. and Schultz-Nielsen, Marie-Louise (2008). “The Construction of Neighbourhoods and its Relevance for the Measurement of Social and Ethnic Segregation: Evidence from Denmark.” Aarhus School of Business, Department of Economics WP 08-17.

Graham, Carol and Felton, Andrew (2006). “Inequality and happiness: Insights from Latin America.” Journal of Economic Inequality, 4, 107-122.

Helliwell, John F. and Huang, Haifang (2005). “How’s the job? Well-being and social capital in the workplace.” NBER Working Paper No. 11759.

Kingdon, Geeta and Knight, John (2007). “Community, comparisons and subjective well-being in a divided society.” Journal of Economic Behaviour &

Organization, 64, 69-90.

Luttmer, Erzo F.P. (2005). “Neighbors as Negatives: Relative Earnings and Well- Being.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 963-1002.

McBride, Michael (2007). “Money, Happiness, and Aspirations: An Experimental Study.” University of California-Irvine, Working Paper 060721.

(12)

Figure 1. Satisfaction with Economic Conditions. Danish ECHP (1994-2001)

3.11

4.98

11.04

23.56

32.94

24.38

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35

1 2 3 4 5 6

Satisfaction with Economic Conditions

Percentage

(13)

Figure 2. Small neighbourhoods in the area of Taastrupgård, Høje Tåstrup

Source: Damm and Schultz-Nielsen (2008).

(14)

Table 1. Economic Satisfaction, Income and Rank within Small Neighbourhoods:

Panel Results

Baseline Baseline and Municipality

Baseline and Rank

Ln(individual earnings) 0.390** 0.390** 0.070*

(0.021) (0.021) (0.028)

Ln(median neighbourhood HH income) 0.228** 0.236** 0.634**

(0.052) (0.055) (0.057)

Ln(median municipality HH income) --- -0.062 ---

--- (0.156) ---

Relative rank in small neighbourhood --- --- 1.124**

--- --- (0.068)

See Neighbours Often -0.019 -0.019 -0.016

(0.016) (0.016) (0.016)

Single -0.057* -0.057* 0.025

(0.027) (0.027) (0.028)

Health problems dummy -0.023 -0.023 -0.023

(0.017) (0.017) (0.017)

Age dummies (9) Yes Yes Yes

Education dummies (6) Yes Yes Yes

Socio-Economic Group dummies (3) Yes Yes Yes

No. and Ages of children dummies (5) Yes Yes Yes No. Years in Neighbourhood dummies

(5)

Yes Yes Yes

Regional dummies (13) Yes Yes Yes

Year dummies (8) Yes Yes Yes

Observations 33 870 33 870 33 870

Notes:Standard errors in parentheses; * significant at the 5% level; ** significant at the 1% level.

These regressions refer to individuals observed in 4,095 small neighbourhoods. These are linear fixed-effect (“within”) regressions.

(15)

Department of Economics:

Skriftserie/Working Paper:

2003:

WP 03-1 Søren Harck: Er der nu en strukturelt bestemt langsigts-ledighed i SMEC?: Phillipskurven i SMEC 99 vis-à-vis SMEC 94. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-2 Beatrice Schindler Rangvid: Evaluating Private School Quality in Denmark. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-3 Tor Eriksson: Managerial Pay and Executive Turnover in the Czech and Slovak Republics. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-4 Michael Svarer and Mette Verner: Do Children Stabilize Marriages? ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-5 Christian Bjørnskov and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen: Measuring social capital – Is there a single underlying explanation? ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-6 Vibeke Jakobsen and Nina Smith: The educational attainment of the children of the Danish ‘guest worker’ immigrants. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-7 Anders Poulsen: The Survival and Welfare Implications of Altruism When Preferences are Endogenous. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-8 Helena Skyt Nielsen and Mette Verner: Why are Well-educated Women not Full-timers? ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-9 Anders Poulsen: On Efficiency, Tie-Breaking Rules and Role Assignment Procedures in Evolutionary Bargaining. ISSN 1397- 4831.

WP 03-10 Anders Poulsen and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen: Rise and Decline

of Social Capital

(16)

WP 03-11 Nabanita Datta Gupta and Amaresh Dubey: Poverty and Fertility: An Instrumental Variables Analysis on Indian Micro Data. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-12 Tor Eriksson: The Managerial Power Impact on Compensation – Some Further Evidence. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-13 Christian Bjørnskov: Corruption and Social Capital. ISSN 1397- 4831.

WP 03-14 Debashish Bhattacherjee: The Effects of Group Incentives in an Indian Firm

– Evidence from Payroll Data. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-15 Tor Eriksson och Peter Jensen: Tidsbegränsade anställninger – danska erfarenheter. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-16 Tom Coupé, Valérie Smeets and Frédéric Warzynski: Incentives, Sorting and Productivity along the Career: Evidence from a Sample of Top Economists. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-17 Jozef Koning, Patrick Van Cayseele and Frédéric Warzynski:

The Effects of Privatization and Competitive Pressure on Firms’

Price-Cost Margins: Micro Evidence from Emerging Economies.

ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-18 Urs Steiner Brandt and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen: The coalition of industrialists and environmentalists in the climate change issue. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-19 Jan Bentzen: An empirical analysis of gasoline price convergence for 20 OECD countries. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-20 Jan Bentzen and Valdemar Smith: Regional income convergence in the Scandinavian countries. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-21 Gert Tinggaard Svendsen: Social Capital, Corruption and Economic Growth: Eastern and Western Europe. ISSN 1397- 4831.

WP 03-22 Jan Bentzen and Valdemar Smith: A Comparative Study of

(17)

WP 03-23 Peter Guldager: Folkepensionisternes incitamenter til at arbejde.

ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-24 Valérie Smeets and Frédéric Warzynski: Job Creation, Job Destruction and Voting Behavior in Poland. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-25 Tom Coupé, Valérie Smeets and Frédéric Warzynski: Incentives in Economic Departments: Testing Tournaments? ISSN 1397- 4831.

WP 03-26 Erik Strøjer Madsen, Valdemar Smith and Mogens Dilling- Hansen: Industrial clusters, firm location and productivity – Some empirical evidence for Danish firms. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 03-27 Aycan Çelikaksoy, Helena Skyt Nielsen and Mette Verner:

Marriage Migration: Just another case of positive assortative matching? ISSN 1397-4831.

2004:

WP 04-1 Elina Pylkkänen and Nina Smith: Career Interruptions due to Parental Leave – A Comparative Study of Denmark and Sweden.

ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-2 Urs Steiner Brandt and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen: Switch Point and First-Mover Advantage: The Case of the Wind Turbine Industry. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-3 Tor Eriksson and Jaime Ortega: The Adoption of Job Rotation:

Testing the Theories. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-4 Valérie Smeets: Are There Fast Tracks in Economic Departments? Evidence from a Sample of Top Economists.

ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-5 Karsten Bjerring Olsen, Rikke Ibsen and Niels Westergaard- Nielsen: Does Outsourcing Create Unemployment? The Case of the Danish Textile and Clothing Industry. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-6 Tor Eriksson and Johan Moritz Kuhn: Firm Spin-offs in

(18)

WP 04-7 Mona Larsen and Nabanita Datta Gupta: The Impact of Health on Individual Retirement Plans: a Panel Analysis comparing Self-reported versus Diagnostic Measures. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-8 Christian Bjørnskov: Inequality, Tolerance, and Growth. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-9 Christian Bjørnskov: Legal Quality, Inequality, and Tolerance.

ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-10 Karsten Bjerring Olsen: Economic Cooperation and Social Identity: Towards a Model of Economic Cross-Cultural Integration. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-11 Iben Bolvig: Within- and between-firm mobility in the low-wage labour market. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-12 Odile Poulsen and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen: Social Capital and Market Centralisation: A Two-Sector Model. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-13 Aditya Goenka and Odile Poulsen: Factor Intensity Reversal and Ergodic Chaos. ISSN 1397-4831.

WP 04-14 Jan Bentzen and Valdemar Smith: Short-run and long-run relationships in the consumption of alcohol in the Scandinavian countries.

ISBN 87-7882-010-3 (print); ISBN 87-7882-011-1 (online).

WP 04-15 Jan Bentzen, Erik Strøjer Madsen, Valdemar Smith and Mogens Dilling-Hansen: Persistence in Corporate Performance?

Empirical Evidence from Panel Unit Root Tests.

ISBN 87-7882-012-X (print); ISBN 87-7882-013-8 (online).

WP 04-16 Anders U. Poulsen and Jonathan H.W. Tan: Can Information Backfire? Experimental Evidence from the Ultimatum Game.

ISBN 87-7882-014-6 (print); ISBN 87-7882-015-4 (online).

WP 04-17 Werner Roeger and Frédéric Warzynski: A Joint Estimation of Price-Cost Margins and Sunk Capital: Theory and Evidence from the European Electricity Industry.

ISBN 87-7882-016-2 (print); ISBN 87-7882-017-0 (online).

(19)

WP 04-18 Nabanita Datta Gupta and Tor Eriksson: New workplace practices and the gender wage gap.

ISBN 87-7882-018-9 (print); ISBN 87-7882-019-7 (online).

WP 04-19 Tor Eriksson and Axel Werwatz: The Prevalence of Internal Labour Markets – New Evidence from Panel Data.

ISBN 87-7882-020-0 (print); ISBN 87-7882-021-9 (online).

WP 04-20 Anna Piil Damm and Michael Rosholm: Employment Effects of Dispersal Policies on Refugee Immigrants: Empirical Evidence.

ISBN 87-7882-022-7 (print); ISBN 87-7882-023-5 (online).

2005:

WP 05-1 Anna Piil Damm and Michael Rosholm: Employment Effects of Dispersal Policies on Refugee Immigrants: Theory.

ISBN 87-7882-024-3 (print); ISBN 87-7882-025-1 (online).

WP 05-2 Anna Piil Damm: Immigrants’ Location Preferences: Exploiting a Natural Experiment.

ISBN 87-7882-036-7 (print); ISBN 87-7882-037-5 (online).

WP 05-3 Anna Piil Damm: The Danish Dispersal Policy on Refugee Immigrants 1986-1998: A Natural Experiment?

ISBN 87-7882-038-3 (print); ISBN 87-7882-039-1 (online).

WP 05-4 Rikke Ibsen and Niels Westergaard-Nielsen: Job Creation and Destruction over the Business Cycles and the Impact on Individual Job Flows in Denmark 1980-2001.

ISBN 87-7882-040-5 (print); ISBN 87-7882-041-3 (online).

WP 05-5 Anna Maria Kossowska, Nina Smith, Valdemar Smith and Mette Verner: Til gavn for bundlinjen – Forbedrer kvinder i topledelse og bestyrelse danske virksomheders bundlinje?

ISBN 87-7882-042-1 (print); ISBN 87-7882-043-X (online).

WP 05-6 Odile Poulsen and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen: The Long and Winding Road: Social Capital and Commuting.

ISBN 87-7882-044-8 (print); ISBN 87-7882-045-6 (online).

(20)

WP 05-8 Christian Bjørnskov: Political Ideology and Economic Freedom.

ISBN 87-7882-064-2 (print); ISBN 87-7882-065-0 (online).

WP 05-9 Sebastian Buhai and Coen Teulings: Tenure Profiles and Efficient Separation in a Stochastic Productivity Model.

ISBN 87-7882-066-9 (print); ISBN 87-7882-067-7 (online).

WP 05-10 Christian Grund and Niels Westergård-Nielsen: Age Structure of the Workforce and Firm Performance.

ISBN 87-7882-068-5 (print); ISBN 87-7882-069-3 (online).

WP 05-11 Søren Harck: AD-AS på dansk.

ISBN 87-7882-070-7 (print); ISBN 87-7882-071-5 (online).

WP 05-12 Søren Harck: Hviler Dansk Økonomi på en Cobb-Douglas teknologi?

ISBN 87-7882-092-8 (print); ISBN 87-7882-093-6 (online).

2006:

WP 06-1 Nicolai Kristensen and Edvard Johansson: New Evidence on Cross-Country Differences in Job Satisfaction Using Anchoring Vignettes.

ISBN 87-7882-094-4 (print); ISBN 87-7882-095-2 (online).

WP 06-2 Christian Bjørnskov: How Does Social Trust Affect Economic Growth?

ISBN 87-7882-096-0 (print); ISBN 87-7882-097-9 (online).

WP 06-3 Jan Bentzen, Erik Strøjer Madsen and Valdemar Smith: The Growth Opportunities for SMEs?

ISBN 87-7882-098-7 (print); ISBN 87-7882-099-5 (online).

WP 06-4 Anna Piil Damm: Ethnic Enclaves and Immigrant Labour Market Outcomes: Quasi-Experimental Evidence.

ISBN 87-7882-100-2 (print); ISBN 87-7882-101-0 (online).

WP 06-5 Svend Jespersen, Nicolai Kristensen og Lars Skipper: En kritik af VEU-udvalgets arbejde.

ISBN 87-7882-159-2 (print); ISBN 87-7882-160-6 (online).

(21)

WP 06-7 Jürgen Bitzer, Wolfram Schrettl and Philipp J.H. Schröder:

Intrinsic Motivation versus Signaling in Open Source Software Development.

ISBN 87-7882-163-0 (print); ISBN 87-7882-164-9 (online).

WP 06-8 Valérie Smeets, Kathryn Ierulli and Michael Gibbs: Mergers of Equals & Unequals.

ISBN 87-7882-165-7 (print); ISBN 87-7882-166-5 (online).

WP 06-9 Valérie Smeets: Job Mobility and Wage Dynamics.

ISBN 87-7882-167-3 (print); ISBN 87-7882-168-1 (online).

WP 06-10 Valérie Smeets and Frédéric Warzynski: Testing Models of Hierarchy: Span of Control, Compensation and Career Dynamics.

ISBN 87-7882-187-8 (print); ISBN 87-7882-188-6 (online).

WP 06-11 Sebastian Buhai and Marco van der Leij: A Social Network Analysis of Occupational Segregation.

ISBN 87-7882-189-4 (print); ISBN 87-7882-190-8 (online).

2007:

WP 07-1 Christina Bjerg, Christian Bjørnskov and Anne Holm: Growth, Debt Burdens and Alleviating Effects of Foreign Aid in Least Developed Countries.

ISBN 87-7882-191-6 (print); ISBN 87-7882-192-4 (online).

WP 07-2 Jeremy T. Fox and Valérie Smeets: Do Input Quality and Structural Productivity Estimates Drive Measured Differences in Firm Productivity?

ISBN 87-7882-193-2 (print); ISBN 87-7882-194-0 (online).

WP 07-3 Elisabetta Trevisan: Job Security and New Restrictive Permanent Contracts. Are Spanish Workers More Worried of Losing Their Job?

ISBN 87-7882-195-9 (print); ISBN 87-7882-196-7 (online).

WP 07-4 Tor Eriksson and Jaime Ortega: Performance Pay and the “Time

(22)

WP 07-5 Johan Moritz Kuhn: My Pay is Too Bad (I Quit). Your Pay is Too Good (You’re Fired).

ISBN 9788778822093 (print); ISBN 9788778822109 (online).

WP 07-6 Christian Bjørnskov: Social trust and the growth of schooling.

ISBN 9788778822116 (print); ISBN 9788778822123 (online).

WP 07-7 Jan Bentzen and Valdemar Smith: Explaining champagne prices in Scandinavia – what is the best predictor?

ISBN 9788778822130 (print); ISBN 9788778822147 (online).

WP 07-8 Sandra Cavaco, Jean-Michel Etienne and Ali Skalli: Identifying causal paths between health and socio-economic status:

Evidence from European older workforce surveys

ISBN 9788778822154 (print); ISBN 9788778822161 (online).

WP 07-9 Søren Harck: Long-run properties of some Danish macro- econometric models: an analytical approach.

ISBN 9788778822390 (print); ISBN 9788778822406 (online).

WP 07-10 Takao Kato and Hideo Owan: Market Characteristics, Intra-Firm Coordination, and the Choice of Human Resource Management Systems: Evidence from New Japanese Data.

ISBN 9788778822413 (print); ISBN 9788778822420 (online).

WP 07-11 Astrid Würtz: The Long-Term Effect on Children of Increasing the Length of Parents’ Birth-Related Leave.

ISBN 9788778822437 (print); ISBN 9788778822444 (online).

WP 07-12 Tor Eriksson and Marie-Claire Villeval: Performance Pay, Sorting and Social Motivation.

ISBN 9788778822451 (print); ISBN 9788778822468 (online).

WP 07-13 Jane Greve: Obesity and Labor Market Outcomes: New Danish Evidence.

ISBN 9788778822475 (print); ISBN 9788778822482 (online).

2008:

WP 08-1 Sebastian Buhai, Miguel Portela, Coen Teulings and Aico van

(23)

WP 08-2 Flora Bellone, Patrick Musso, Lionel Nesta et Frédéric Warzynski: L’effet pro-concurrentiel de l’intégration européenne : une analyse de l’évolution des taux de marge dans les industries manufacturières françaises

ISBN 9788778822857 (print); ISBN 9788778822864 (online).

WP 08-3 Erdal Yalcin: The Proximity-Concentration Trade-Off under Goods Price and Exchange Rate Uncertainty

ISBN 9788778822871 (print); ISBN 9788778822888 (online)

WP 08-4 Elke J. Jahn and Herbert Brücker: Migration and the Wage Curve: A Structural Approach to Measure the Wage and Employment Effects of Migration

ISBN 9788778822895 (print); ISBN 9788778822901 (online)

WP 08-5 Søren Harck: A Phillips curve interpretation of error-correction models of the wage and price dynamics

ISBN 9788778822918 (print); ISBN 9788778822925 (online)

WP 08-6 Elke J. Jahn and Thomas Wagner: Job Security as an Endogenous Job Characteristic

ISBN 9788778823182 (print); ISBN 9788778823199 (online)

WP 08-7 Jørgen Drud Hansen, Virmantas Kvedaras and Jørgen Ulff- Møller Nielsen: Monopolistic Competition, International Trade and Firm Heterogeneity - a Life Cycle Perspective -

ISBN 9788778823212 (print); ISBN 9788778823229 (online)

WP 08-8 Dario Pozzoli: The Transition to Work for Italian University Graduates

ISBN 9788778823236 (print); ISBN 9788778823243 (online)

WP 08-9 Annalisa Cristini and Dario Pozzoli: New Workplace Practices and Firm Performance: a Comparative Study of Italy and Britain ISBN 9788778823250 (print); ISBN 9788778823267 (online)

WP 08-10 Paolo Buonanno and Dario Pozzoli: Early Labour Market Returns to College Subjects

ISBN 9788778823274 (print); ISBN 9788778823281 (online)

(24)

WP 08-12 Nina Smith, Valdemar Smith and Mette Verner: Women in Top Management and Firm Performance

ISBN 9788778823465 (print); ISBN 9788778823472 (online)

WP 08-13 Sebastian Buhai, Elena Cottini and Niels Westergård-Nielsen:

The impact of workplace conditions on firm performance ISBN 9788778823496 (print); ISBN 9788778823502 (online)

WP 08-14 Michael Rosholm: Experimental Evidence on the Nature of the Danish Employment Miracle

ISBN 9788778823526 (print); ISBN 9788778823533 (online)

WP 08-15 Christian Bjørnskov and Peter Kurrild-Klitgaard: Economic Growth and Institutional Reform in Modern Monarchies and Republics: A Historical Cross-Country Perspective 1820-2000 ISBN 9788778823540 (print); ISBN 9788778823557 (online)

WP 08-16 Nabanita Datta Gupta, Nicolai Kristensen and Dario Pozzoli:

The Validity of Vignettes in Cross-Country Health Studies ISBN 9788778823694 (print); ISBN 9788778823700 (online)

WP 08-17 Anna Piil Damm and Marie Louise Schultz-Nielsen: The Construction of Neighbourhoods and its Relevance for the Measurement of Social and Ethnic Segregation: Evidence from Denmark

ISBN 9788778823717 (print); ISBN 9788778823724 (online)

WP 08-18 Jørgen Drud Hansen and Jørgen Ulff-Møller Nielsen: Price as an Indicator for Quality in International Trade?

ISBN 9788778823731 (print); ISBN 9788778823748 (online)

WP 08-19 Elke J. Jahn and John Wegner: Do Targeted Hiring Subsidies and Profiling Techniques Reduce Unemployment?

ISBN 9788778823755 (print); ISBN 9788778823762 (online)

WP 08-20 Flora Bellone, Patrick Musso, Lionel Nesta and Frederic

Warzynski: Endogenous Markups, Firm Productivity and

International Trade: Testing Some Micro-Level Implications of

the Melitz-Ottaviano Model

(25)

WP 08-21 Linda Bell, Nina Smith, Valdemar Smith and Mette Verner:

Gender differences in promotion into top-management jobs ISBN 9788778823830 (print); ISBN 9788778823847(online)

WP 08-22 Jan Bentzen and Valdemar Smith: An empirical analysis of the relationship between the consumption of alcohol and liver cirrhosis mortality

ISBN 9788778823854 (print); ISBN 9788778823861(online)

WP 08-23 Gabriel J. Felbermayr, Sanne Hiller and Davide Sala: Does Immigration Boost Per Capita Income?

ISBN 9788778823878 (print); ISBN 9788778823885(online)

WP 08-24 Christian Gormsen: Anti-Dumping with Heterogeneous Firms:

New Protectionism for the New-New Trade Theory

ISBN 9788778823892 (print); ISBN 9788778823908 (online)

WP 08-25 Andrew E. Clark, Nicolai Kristensen and Niels Westergård- Nielsen: Economic Satisfaction and Income Rank in Small Neighbourhoods

ISBN 9788778823915 (print); ISBN 9788778823922 (online)

Referencer

RELATEREDE DOKUMENTER

The analyses show that most Danish households use some type of income pooling and that the likelihood of income pooling varies considerably according to individual

We designed a mixed-method field test to compare human resources reporting efforts, data accuracy and completeness, and timeliness of submitting data reports from the health

Consequently, a data-driven approach to value creation in the public museum field entails that museums work strategically with Big Data in order to generate

1 See e.g., OECD, Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy – Action 1: Final Report in OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, (OECD Publishing 2015), Chapter

The results relate to both new and updated measurements of com- positional traits of bovine milk from individual cows sampled as part of the project The updated measurements

This subsection studies how municipality NPIs affected excess influenza mortality rates, and short-run economic income growth, followed by an analysis of how the bank sector

The lack of fit for the medieval sample indicates that sensitivity and specificity measures derived from modern American skeletons do not capture the nature of the early Ribe

types contains a number of entity classes derived from the data types in the Types module in the model. statics contains a number of classes derived from the Statics module in